Introduction to Parxeogenic Economics Part 4
- Dr. Byron Gillory
- May 15
- 4 min read
The Birth of Praxeogenic Economics Part 3
The Intellectual Genealogy of Praxeogenic Economics
From the Marginal Revolution to Methodological Divergence
To fully understand the emergence of Praxeogenic Economics, one must examine its lineage. While it is grounded in Austrian foundations, its birth required an intellectual evolution beyond the original framework. The seeds were planted in the Marginal Revolution of the 1870s, with Carl Menger standing as a pivotal figure. Menger’s insight into subjective value theory and causal-realist methodology departed radically from the classical cost-of-production theories of Smith and Ricardo. He insisted that economics must begin with the acting individual and that value arises not from labor or utility in the abstract but from the ranked preferences of the individual decision-maker.
This Mengerian vision was not an isolated moment but the inception of a deeper philosophical trajectory. His successors—Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, Ludwig von Mises, and later Murray Rothbard—continued this path. They emphasized time, uncertainty, capital heterogeneity, and the role of the entrepreneur. Most importantly, they retained a firm commitment to the deductive method: beginning from the axiom of action and reasoning logically to uncover economic laws.
Yet, even within Austrian thought, certain structural limitations remained. While Mises developed praxeology with unprecedented clarity, and Rothbard advanced a complete treatise in Man, Economy, and State, the tradition had not formalized tools to model formation, visualize structure, or engage with data without compromising its epistemological integrity. Moreover, by the late 20th century, Austrian economics had become more reactive than constructive—focused on critique rather than innovation.
Praxeogenic Economics takes this tradition not as an endpoint, but as a foundation. It seeks to finish what the early Austrians began: to build a science of economic formation that is both logically coherent and analytically rich. Its project is not merely conservative but constructive—a new system rooted in Menger, matured by Mises, sharpened by Rothbard, and extended into an integrated dual-discipline field of economics.
Responding to the Failures of Contemporary Paradigms
The dominant schools of the 20th and 21st centuries—Keynesianism, Monetarism, and Neoclassical synthesis—produced enormous intellectual capital but little structural clarity. Keynesian macroeconomics ignored time preference, capital heterogeneity, and entrepreneurial causality. It focused on aggregates, treating investment and consumption as mechanical outputs of monetary policy. It called for centralized intervention and left economists with models that worked on blackboards but failed in real economies.
Monetarism, for all its nominal adherence to market discipline, likewise abstracted away from real structure. Its focus on monetary aggregates, quantity theory, and neutral money left it blind to the effects of credit expansion on the formation and misformation of capital. Meanwhile, the rational expectations revolution substituted one form of abstraction for another: treating individuals as statistical functions with perfect foresight, embedded in DSGE (Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium) models that, in practice, erased the temporal and entrepreneurial core of real economies.
These models failed for a simple reason: they treated action as noise and equilibrium as norm. Praxeogenic Economics, by contrast, treats action as the origin and formation as the norm. The economic order is not a machine to be balanced but a process to be understood—through time, risk, coordination, and subjective judgment.
The Causal Realism of Human Action
Action as the Genesis of Economic Order
In Praxeogenic Economics, all analysis begins with the reality that human beings act purposefully. This Misesian axiom—"man acts"—is not a hypothesis or empirical generalization. It is a logical truth known through introspection and undeniable in both theory and observation. Every economic event—buying, selling, producing, saving, investing—is a result of this fundamental reality.
From this axiom flows the entire architecture of economic understanding:
Ends and Means: Every action aims at an end through chosen means.
Scarcity: Since means are limited, choices must be made.
Opportunity Cost: Choosing one means foregoes another.
Marginal Value: Value is assigned not to goods in general, but to discrete units in context.
Time Preference: Present satisfaction is preferred over future satisfaction, ceteris paribus.
Praxeogenic Economics treats these concepts not as isolated ideas but as formational principles. Human action leads to the creation of economic structure—capital goods, firms, investment networks, pricing mechanisms, and intertemporal production chains. This structure is not static, nor is it imposed from above. It is formed, layer by layer, by acting individuals who interpret uncertain futures and deploy resources accordingly.
Toward a Dynamic Theory of Formation
The traditional Austrian School explained much about capital and time but lacked a dynamic model for how economic formation emerges and evolves. Praxeogenic Economics introduces the formation function—a conceptual bridge between praxeology and real-world economic structure. It does not rely on static equilibrium conditions or marginal utility curves; rather, it maps how entrepreneurial action structures capital across multiple dimensions: time, scale, risk, and conversion.
Thus, when an individual invests in a real estate project, or when a founder launches a startup, they are not simply allocating capital—they are forming economic structure. They are coordinating factors through time, aligning them with subjective valuations, and embedding them within a broader market lattice. This formation is not linear. It is recursive, interpretive, and always subject to revision.
What emerges is a system of layered formation:
First-order formation: The initial act of entrepreneurial insight.
Second-order formation: The structuring of capital goods into production chains.
Third-order formation: The emergence of intertemporal markets, price coordination, and institutional supports.
Praxeogenic Economics is the only framework that systematically models this process while maintaining fidelity to its causal roots.
A Break from Empiricism: The Rejection of Predictive Modeling
Positivism’s Fatal Flaw
Modern economics is obsessed with prediction. The idea that models must forecast GDP, unemployment, or inflation in order to be valid has poisoned the discipline. This stems from a broader intellectual error: positivism—the belief that all knowledge must be derived from sensory data and statistical relationships.
Praxeogenic Economics rejects this premise entirely. It affirms that causal understanding precedes statistical correlation, and that prediction, when it occurs, must be logically grounded, not mechanically extrapolated. Mises made this point sharply: economics is a theoretical science, not an empirical one. It is not a science of what happens, but of what must happen when certain conditions are met (e.g., if money supply increases without corresponding demand for money, prices must rise).
Praxeogenic Economics retains this view but pushes it forward. It recognizes the value of illustration, diagnosis, and measurement, but it insists that these must be derived from theory, not imposed upon it.
Comments