Reconstructing Economic Education with Praxeogenic Tools
- Dr. Byron Gillory
- May 27
- 2 min read
A. Escaping the Two-Track Trap
Modern economics education tends to bifurcate into two disjointed tracks:
Abstract theory, often taught as an exercise in mathematical modeling and symbolic manipulation devoid of interpretive clarity.
Empirical analysis, taught as data science under an economic banner—where theories are fitted to data rather than data interpreted through theory.
Praxeogenic Economics rejects this false dichotomy. It offers a unified pedagogy that teaches theory as deductive and structural, and empirical tools as illustrative and interpretive. It trains economists not to model the world as a machine but to understand the world as an evolving formation brought forth by action.
B. Curriculum Reform: From Foundations to Formation
A Praxeogenic curriculum could be structured into three foundational streams:
1. Action and Structure (Praxeology and Formational Economics): Students begin with the logic of action, marginal choice, subjective value, time preference, and capital layering—learning not from assumptions but from the logical necessities of acting under uncertainty.
2. Visualization and Diagnostic Tools (Austrian Econometrics): Next, students learn to work with the CFM, IMI, and DPW as interpretive tools. These aren’t predictive instruments, but maps of structure, clarity, and misalignment.
3. Historical and Institutional Applications: Students engage with real-world episodes (e.g., the 1920s, 1970s, 2000s, COVID-19 response) through Praxeogenic lenses—showing how errors, distortions, and recoveries followed specific patterns visible only through this framework.
C. Forming Economic Thinkers, Not Technicians
More than producing data analysts or model optimizers, Praxeogenic education seeks to form thinkers—those who grasp economic processes from first principles, interpret them from a causal standpoint, and communicate insights clearly to students, policymakers, and entrepreneurs. This educational vision is central to the future of the discipline.
Policy Implications and Ethical Commitments
A. The Anti-Managerial Ethic
One of the most radical conclusions of Praxeogenic Economics is its ethical stance against technocracy. Because economic orders are emergent and human action is creative and uncertain, no bureaucrat, planner, or central banker can manage the economy. Any attempt to do so results in:
Misallocation of capital.
Suppression of entrepreneurial discovery.
Institutional distortion.
Crisis followed by greater interventionism.
Praxeogenic theory therefore calls for minimal state involvement, sound money, free prices, and private property not as ideological commitments, but as preconditions for the formation of sustainable economic order.
B. Ethical Foundations of Action
Moreover, Praxeogenic Economics affirms that economics is not value-neutral. If economics is rooted in human action, then it must respect:
The dignity of persons as agents.
The freedom to choose, err, and recover.
The moral responsibility of entrepreneurship—not merely profit-seeking, but judgment under uncertainty in service of others through market exchange.
This ethical framework rejects both the nihilism of relativistic economics and the paternalism of technocratic control. It affirms freedom and responsibility as economic and moral necessities.
C. Policy Prudence and Humility
Because it does not pretend to predict outcomes or design optimal allocations, Praxeogenic policy recommendations emphasize prudence, restraint, and humility. Good policy:
Removes barriers to formation.
Avoids inflationary finance.
Allows the structure of production to emerge organically from savings, investment, and discovery.
Respects the limits of knowledge and rejects intervention for intervention’s sake.
Praxeogenic policy is thus neither right-wing nor left-wing—it is formation-centered, freedom-based, and institutionally realist.
Comments